(1) What is your opinion on the recent sub 1% participation rates (% of holders) in dao votings on Aragon, maker & 0x respective daos. What are the main reasons for that?
First, we need to consider what we classify as a āDAO,ā and neither Aragon nor 0x really fit the elegant description of a DAO as initially proposed by Vitalik:
Automation at the center, humans at the edges.
Why is this the case?
Foremost, both 0x and Aragon both have centralized proposal curation. In the case of 0x, the only rights token holders have are a veto authority. For Aragon, proposals undergo curation first by āAGP Editorsā (two handpicked individuals by the Aragon team) and then a 3-man association. In both of these cases, the relationship Vitalik describes is explicitly inverted: humans are at the center, and automation (the actual nuts and bolts execution of proposals by the blockchain) exists at the edges.
MakerDAO is different, as large portions of their governance exists on and is automated by a blockchain, yet has the same issue with participation. What gives?
In MakerDAOās governance article, they explicitly hint at the problem:
Combined with the majority wins tenet, it should be clear that the main responsibility of MKR token holders is to be cognizant of all proposals that enter the voting construct. In fact, the lack of quorum implicitly incentivizes all MKR token holders to be involved.
⦠but, they fail to articulate a solution to this issue: rather, they anticipate that participation will be an incentive-in-itself. However, we understand this isnāt usually the case, through a concept called Rational Ignorance:
Rational ignorance is refraining from acquiring knowledge when the cost of educating oneself on an issue exceeds the potential benefit that the knowledge would provide.
The cost/benefit analysis of voting can be applied to both the Aragon and 0x cases as well in a similar way: why would anyone feel incentivized to thoroughly research proposals and vote when a handful of highly curated proposals are the only proposals brought to the table? The most extreme case is 0x, where their last proposal was a technical upgrade presented by their dev team.
Generally, your question is really getting at costs of voting, and what motivates people to pay these costs by participating. The answer to your Q is: the costs are too damn high! When we consider that thereās no cost to not voting ā since the experts already figured out the best proposals to vote on anyway ā and that the results are largely certain (to date I believe only 1 AGP has been vetoed) ā it becomes clear why thereās no real participation in their system.
(2) how would you tackle the issue of most people not voting, especially due to the prevalent technical risks associated with using unproven smart contracts / removing funds from cold storage
Thereās three Qs here:
i. How do you tackle the issue of most people not voting
ii. How do you address technical risks
iii. How do you address UX friction in voting (removing funds from cold storage)
Iāll answer them 1-by-1:
i.) In the DAOstack framework, we actively consider the costs of voting to the collective attention of the voters, and have designed a consensus protocol around it. The protocol is designed, actually, not to increase participation in the voting for every proposal submitted, but to ensure that there is alignment with the entire voter pool even when participation is low. The DAOstack Whitepaper (pg 22) discusses the mechanics of aptly named āholographic consensusā in detail:
In holographic consensus we want to eliminate possible mismatches between decisions made by small groups on behalf of the greater majority and the decision that would have been made by the greater majority itself, if enough attention was available. To eliminate possible mismatches, we introduce a novel prediction game, in which anyone ā not necessarily a DAO reputation holder ā can place predictions, backed by stake, on the fate of proposals⦠Correct predictors make profits, and incorrect ones lose their stake. By playing the prediction game predictors contribute to the governance process by signaling to, filtering and maintaining the governance process.
ā¦
Finding out these social mismatches, or inefficiencies, is the most important part of making a collective attention more efficient and a governance system more scalable. By providing stake-backed predictions, the predictors provide valuable signals to the governing network about proposals that are under or over evaluated⦠once a proposal is being boosted, there is enough predictorsā skin in the game to make sure the process is effective and that whoever needs to be participating indeed participated. We use crypto-economics incentives to āoutsourceā the navigation of the collectiveattention of DAOs to a professional network of predictors.
The main takeaway from all of this is that with our solution we are not trying to boost participation for every decision taken by a DAO; in fact, we would argue that this is a bad thing as it risks tiring out the collective attention of the voters, especially if there is a large frequency of decisions to take. Holographic consensus tactically aims to boost participation when there is ambiguity as to whether a proposalās expected outcome is aligned or not with the presumed outcome of all DAO members participating.
Additionally, there are some main technical differences between DAOstack and the aforementioned token voting systems discussed, the foremost being that Alchemy Earth is optimized as a Reputation voting system. Two recent posts describe this in detail:
A Guide to DAOstackās Initial Reputation Protocol
Reputation vs. Tokens
Generally, with our Reputation voting system, proposals tend to have a greater level of participation than the original token voting examples presented.
ii.) Our opinion is that technical risks are best approached through community bug bounties and extensive auditing. One example is the dxDAO bug bounty, which successfully resulted in a bug being reported. Weāve worked together with ChainSecurity on DAOstackās smart contracts as auditor ā for reference, they were the ones who caught the Ethereum Constantinople launch bug prior to the fork.
But ā more than this ā itās important to start by managing small sums of funds, and then scaling up to larger fund management. Good risk management is the best way to start transitioning to a decentralized treasury, something the original DAO didnāt practice.
iii.) Moving funds out of cold storage for the purposes of voting does not exist with DAOstack, because it uses a Reputation based voting system. So you can keep your tokens tidily tucked away without the hassle of moving them back and forth.
3) is it more efficient for a project like kyber to remove its centralized governance now that ensures speed of decision making or would you recommend to do it later after a certain traction has been proven and decision making can be conducted slower and require more decentralization?
A lot of this depends on what aspects of Kyber youāre trying to decentralize. With most orgs, and especially blockchain projects managing a decentralized application, thereās a wide space to play in.
Does Kyber want to decentralizeā¦
- A microgrants process, to develop and promote the project?
- The management of its applicationās smart contracts, so the DAO becomes the owner and effective controller?
- The curation of a registry of tokens listed on KyberNetwork?
ā¦etc
My take on it is to run a pilot decentralizing the simplest items first, such as a microgrants process, before looking at bigger picture items, such as the application itself, or a token registry. So I would say: after a certain traction has formed, in a low-risk, no stakes environment, with a small sum of funds (perhaps $10k/month worth of KNC, ETH, DAIā¦)
One thing to consider: thereās no reason a business with a specific set of KPIs to hit cannot exist as a sub-agency within a larger DAO. In fact, it might be valuable for a big āAlliance DAOā to have one or multiple businesses sitting within it, acting in the interests of the crowd, receiving grants as part of the ecosystem.
4) what metrics would you propose to measure the successful implementation of a dao?
Some questions to ask:
- Is the DAO being effectively managed by a small association of managerial operators, or through a widely decentralized crowd of greater than Dunbarās Number?
- Does the DAO have a source of sustainable revenue, so it can continue to grow and support itself?
- Is the DAO receiving many proposals for different types of jobs ā such as community growth, product development, and content creation ā or just a few proposals focusing on a very narrow perspective?
- Is the DAOās activity growing (in terms of participating voters) or shrinking?
There are different success metrics for a DAO, but I think these are the most important from the get-go.